So what does Keynes object to in classical
theory? He starts with the classical
theory of the labour market. This, he
says, is based on two fundamental postulates.
The first is that the wage is equal to the marginal product of
labour. He defines this as the value
which would be lost if employment were to be reduced by one unit, and from his
terminology he seems to be referring to the nominal wage. On the demand for labour curve front, JMK is
pretty classical – we seem here to be looking at the thing we would call the
value of the marginal product, meaning, in a competitive economy (which JMK for
the most part assumes) price times the marginal physical product curve of
labour. No problems here – it’s the
second postulate which JMK objects to.
That postulate is that “the utility of the
wage when a given volume of labour is employed is equal to the marginal
disutility of that amount of employment”.
Keynes then goes on to say that this means that the real wage is just
sufficient to “induce the volume of labour actually employed to be
forthcoming”. The real wage (notice the
“real” part) just compensates for the disutility of a certain volume of
labour. Or as we might put it, the real
wage is the supply price of that quantity of labour.
These two postulates, JMK says, give us the
demand and supply curves of labour, and in classical theory the actual level of
employment is at their intersection, labour market equilibrium, where “the
utility of the marginal product balances the disutility of the marginal
employment”.
We’ll get to JMK’s critique of this in a
bit – remember that what he’s doing at this stage is setting out what he sees
as the classical theory. As part of
that, he notes that classical theory does recognize two kinds of
unemployment. One is frictional
unemployment, which just represents impediments to the bringing together of
unemployed workers and unfilled jobs. We
use the same term today – the fact that there are always some people moving
between jobs is the reason we tend to define full employment as meaning somewhere
around three or four percent unemployment (the Australians, in an earlier
period of mineral boom, once defined it as about two percent unemployment, and
the Swiss are said, once upon a time, to have regarded it as disastrous when
unemployment rose above one per cent).
Keynes says the same thing about frictional unemployment as we do - it can be reduced by making labour market
institutions work more efficiently.
Classical theory, as JMK sees it, also
admits of voluntary unemployment:
“unemployment due to the refusal
or inability of a unit of labour, as a result of legislation or social
practices or of combination for collective bargaining or of slow response to
change or of mere human obstinacy, to accept a reward corresponding to the
value of the product attributable to its marginal productivity”
Sounds like
unemployment due to wage stickiness, doesn’t it? Remember that we’re still talking about JMK’s
interpretation of the classical model, not his own model, but you have to be
cautious about saying that Keynesian unemployment is due to downward stickiness
of wages. At the very least because
that’s a disequilibrium explanation of unemployment, not a model of an
unemployment equilibrium.
No comments:
Post a Comment
Note: Only a member of this blog may post a comment.